That shows total factor productivity growth (TFP, though some call it "multifactor") which is a measure of technological progress calculated as a residual: the part of output growth that cannot be explained by increases in factors of production (capital and labor). Another way to think of it is that it is the growth that would occur even if the amount of machinery and equipment as well as labor stayed the same. The CEA's report explains it quite nicely starting on p. 181.
Technological progress is the key determinant of long run living standards, so if the trend of technological progress has risen after its slump in the 1970's and 80's, its a big deal (and a bigger deal than many of the short-run cyclical issues we tend to obsess over).
The CEA's chart shows 15-year averages which smooths out the year-to-year volatility in TFP growth. This is sensible because it its hard to discern the long-run trends that the concept is meant to help us understand. The average TFP growth rate can be split into three eras:
- 1949-1973 -- 1.9%
- 1974-1995 -- 0.4%
- 1996-2012 -- 1.1%
However, the results are somewhat different than what I presented to my macroeconomics students a few weeks ago. This is a chart made from the BLS' Historical Multifactor Productivity Measures for the private non-farm business sector (which I believe is the same data the CEA used).
The gray line is the actual annual growth (you can see why it helps to average out some of the volatility) and the red line is the centered 15-year average (i.e., the same as the CEA's graph). However, the CEA's method of averaging means that their graph stops in 2005. The years since then have not been good ones for TFP. Since their data point for 2005 is an average over the years 1998-2012, the CEA is not ignoring the bad news, but they are lumping it in together with some good years (the late 1990's and early 2000's).
The dashed lines in the chart above illustrate an alternative, less optimistic way of interpreting the same data by breaking it down into four eras instead of three:
- 1949-1973 -- 1.9%
- 1974-1995 -- 0.4%
- 1996-2005 -- 1.6%
- 2006-2012 -- 0.5%
Identification of trends in short periods of volatile data is inherently uncertain, and it may be sensible to think the reduction in TFP growth over the past several years is largely the artifact of cyclical factors. That seems to be, implicitly, the CEA's view (and Ben Bernanke also has argued for a more optimistic interpretation of long-run prospects). Whether they're right or Gordon is will make a huge difference for standards of living a generation or two hence, but, just now, it is too soon to tell.
2 comments:
Interesting post.
Dean Baker and John Schmitt, in The Real Economic Crisis (2007), discuss productivity trends without specifying their measure of productivity. But they do see a four-stage pattern in those trends, similar to yours.
Thanks. It looks like they were referring to "labor productivity" - output per unit of labor. But it, too, is mainly driven by technology so it shows similar trends (one of the interesting things in the CEA report was showing that on average labor productivity is basically total factor productivity + one percentage point).
In any case, I sure hope the White House's more optimistic interpretation is correct. Interesting to speculate about, but its truly one of the things we don't know.
Post a Comment